Thursday, June 28, 2012

An Analysis of the Supreme Court Obamacare Decision


For those of you who are scratching your heads regarding the Obamacare decision, I’ll write this overview for you. 

First, some proper names. While commonly called Obamacare, the name you’ll normally see in the opinion is the Affordable Care Act. And the case that the Supreme Court decided today is National Federation of Independent Business v. Sebelius. You can read the opinion here. Interestingly, at the time of this writing, the Supreme Court website still hasn’t put a formal link to the opinion up. I just happened upon it. (Makes me look forward to the efficiency of government health care.)
Next, the lineup. Four justices--Ginsberg, Sotomayor, Breyer, and Kagan—voted to uphold the entire act, and would have done so on Commerce Clause grounds. I.E., in their view, the federal government can force individuals to engage in commerce, and then impose any regulations it wanted, and thus the individual mandate is OK. (The dissenters pretty accurately claimed that had this come to fruition, federalism would be dead, and I agree with them. If there’s any bright spot in this ruling, it’s that the Supremes (narrowly, by a single vote) failed to expand the commerce power in this fashion. In fact, quite the opposite: The Roberts/Scalia opinions together constitute the third major limitation on the Commerce Power in the past 70 years. As Scalia wrote:



The striking case of Wickard v. Filburn, 317 U.S. 111 (1942), which held that the economic activity of growing wheat, even for one’s own consumption, affected commerce sufficiently that it could be regulated, always has been regarded as the ne plus ultra of expansive Commerce Clause jurisprudence. To go beyond that, and say the failure to grow wheat (which is not an economic activity, or any activity at all) nonetheless affects commerce and therefore can be federally regulated, is to make mere breathing in and out the basis for federal prescription and to extend federal power to virtually all human activity. (Scalia, dissenting, slip opinion at 2-3.)



On the other side of the lineup were Scalia, Kennedy (surprisingly), Alito, and Thomas, who in the dissent uncategorically stated that the ACA is unconstitutional in its entirety. (That’s the surprising thing about Kennedy’s vote. Nothing swingy about that at all. Of course, dissenters have the liberty to be expansive in their denunciations.) 

Then there’s Chief Justice John Roberts. Let’s review for a minute. Nominated by one of the most conservative presidents we’ve had in living memory (George W. Bush), and one of the few judges in living memory to come to the Supreme Court with a proven conservative track record, heartily approved of by the Right. (Of course, we may define conservative in many ways, including not only political positions but matters of judicial activism versus judicial self-restraint.) Roberts wrote a separate opinion. In that opinion he agreed with Scalia et al. on Commerce Clause grounds. But in the key to the whole case, he found the individual mandate to pass constitutional muster on the grounds that it was an Article I Section 8 tax. Since the four justices of Ginsberg et al. also thought the act constitutional (though largely on different grounds, i.e. the Commerce Power), they joined Roberts on the Tax Power ruling, giving the ACA the magic five votes it needed to survive, in its entirety. 

I read in a couple of places immediately after this lineup became clear that several people had foreseen this Roberts decision. Interesting that I heard no hint of that prior to that instant. I think that this came as a shock to everyone, friend and foe of ACA alike. It certainly shocked me, and so I read Roberts’s opinion as soon as I got my hands on it. 

So what’s my analysis of that opinion? Well, if you grant the premise that this is a tax, then Roberts is on pretty solid ground that under the Tax Power, Congress can do this. But that’s a big, and very problematical “if,” and here's where Roberts’s opinion really falls apart. Badly. It reads like something that Rehnquist would have written. I have read some Rehnquist opinions in which a single crucial sentence would have me almost literally banging my head against the wall trying to figure out what it means. There comes a point when someone has to go out of his way to make a meaning obscure, and Rehnquist was good at that. 

Robert’s opinion isn’t quite like that. Instead, it’s just self-contradictory. This is a big problem when you’re attempting to give rational reasons (is that redundant? Apparently not for Roberts) for a decision, which judges are supposed to do. 

I’ll explain. There’s a law on the books from the 1860s called the Anti-Injunction Act. In short, it says that a taxpayer can’t challenge the constitutionality of a tax prospectively. He must wait until he actually has to pay it. Thus, if the individual mandate is mandating a tax for non-insurance buyers, but not for another couple of years, it cannot be challenged yet and the Court can’t give relief in this case. So to hear and rule on this case, Roberts HAD to find that the mandate doesn’t impose a tax. 

The easiest way to do that is to find that what the individual mandate does is to impose not a TAX, but a PENALTY, for failing to buy insurance. That would mean that the Anti-Injunction Act isn’t applicable, because that act speaks only to TAXES. So far so good. 

The problem with finding that the  individual mandate imposes a PENALTY is that Congress has no constitutional power to impose PENALTIES. It may only impose TAXES. So if Roberts declares the mandate to impose a PENALTY, the mandate clears the hurdle of the Anti-Injunction Act only to die as an unconstitutional law that Congress had no power to pass. 

So what did Roberts do? He played word games, plain and simple (if word games can be said to be plain and simple). He said that Congress’s use of the term PENALTY to describe the mandate showed that it didn’t intend the Anti-Injunction Act to apply, even though the so-called PENALTY is actually a TAX. (I’ll call this the “What’s in a Name?” rationale.) I'm not sure where he got the idea that by using the term "penalty," Congress meant to avoid applying the Anti-Injunction Act to the ACA. He just states in a throwaway line "It is up to Congress whether to apply the Anti-Injunction Act to any particular statute, so it makes sense [WHY?] to be guided by Congress's choice of label on that question." (Slip opinion at 33). (Waitaminute! I thought that you were ignoring labels, Chief! Now all of a sudden a mere label is dispositive of the Anti-Injunction Act issue?!)

Then Roberts went on to cite and discuss (slip opinion at 33-35) the 1922 case of Bailey v. Drexel Furniture Co., 259 U.S. 20 (1922). In that case, Congress imposed a what it called a TAX of 10% of a company’s income if the government discovered that company to be employing children. In that case, the Court said it doesn’t matter what you call it (and in that sense it, too, uses the “What’s in a name?” rationale, which is why Roberts cited it. So far so good for Roberts.). If it forces people to either do something or pay money, it’s a PENALTY. In the Drexel Court’s words: 


Does this law impose a tax with only that incidental restraint and regulation which a tax must inevitably involve? Or does it regulate by the use of the so-called tax as a penalty? … If it were an excise on a commodity or other thing of value, we might not be permitted under previous decisions of this court to infer solely from its heavy burden that the act intends a prohibition, instead of a tax. But this act is more. It provides a heavy exaction for a departure from a detailed and specified course of conduct in business. …Taxes are occasionally imposed in the discretion of the legislature on proper subjects with the primary motive of obtaining revenue from them and with the incidental motive of discouraging them by making their continuance onerous. They do not lose their character as taxes because of the incidental motive. But there comes a time in the extension of the penalizing features of the so-called tax when it loses its character as such and becomes a mere penalty with the characteristics of regulation and punishment. Such is the case in the law before us.



(259 U.S. at 37.) The place where Roberts screws up is that the Drexel Court, which he quotes with approval for his “What’s in a name?” approach, finds that the TAX is really a PENALTY. BUT the ACA meets the Drexel Court’s definition of PENALTY. And Congress can’t impose PENALTIES. So under Drexel, the individual mandate should be ruled unconstitutional.
Thus Roberts distorts, and cheats with, the Drexel decision by refusing to note that it compels exactly the opposite conclusion that he reaches. (Of course, that's not so. The Drexel case means exactly what Roberts says it means, since his is the rationale that counts. As Warren Burger once told my father, "We're (i.e., the Supremes) always right.")

So of course Roberts disagrees with my characterization. He notes that the Drexel Court cited three things that convinced it that the Drexel TAX was actually a PENALTY. 1) It involved a bigger tax (or is it penalty?) than the mandate does. 2) It required actual knowledge of violation. 3) The Department of Labor, and not the Treasury, was in charge of enforcement, so it obviously couldn’t be a tax. But there are tons of problems here. The biggest is that under Drexel, these things didn’t make the TAX a PENALTY: they were only evidence that the TAX was a PENALTY. (Again, Roberts would and does disagree with that statement.) The crucial thing for the Drexel Court was that the tax/penalty’s purpose was to make companies do something, just like in the mandate. To quote the Drexel Court (my italics): “In the light of these features of the act, a court must be blind not to see that the so-called tax is imposed to stop the employment of children within the age limits prescribed.” 

Scalia et al. pick up on this, and are far more logical than Roberts. (Scalia always writes good logical opinions, in my view, even when I don’t like the outcome.) In answer to Robert’s “It’s only a little penalty and so it’s OK” rationale, Scalia blows him away. “[W]e have never held—never—that a penalty imposed for violation of the law was so trivial as to be in effect a tax. We have never held that any exaction imposed for violation of the law is an exercise of Congress’ taxing power—even when the statute calls it a tax, much less when (as here) the statute repeatedly calls it a penalty.” (Slip opinion at 19.) The dissent also notes that strict knowledge isn’t a requirement for a PENALTY, and that PENALTIES are often imposed for strict-liability offenses. (Slip opinion at 24.) (Frankly, Scalia should have provided some examples here, but he provides none at all.) As for the Drexel Court’s observation that the penalty/tax was collected by Labor and not Treasury, Scalia hoists Roberts with his own structural petard. The individual mandate’s PENALTY, Scalia points out, isn’t found in the ACA’s revenue provisions (Title IX), but in the core section of Title I. 

In short, Roberts has engaged in a self-serving interpretation and mischaracterization of Drexel, talking too much about the Drexel trees and ignoring the Drexel forest. My guess is that he wanted to go down in history as the man who gave us national health care, and he was willing to engage in sloppy reasoning to do it. In doing so, he’s done a disservice to both the Court and the Constitution; he’s also chosen a path that is certain to enrage conservatives to the point of apoplexy. 

This is not a good decision. This law was a perversion of the democratic process from the beginning. The Democrats shut the Republicans completely out of the process; there was no bipartisan support at all, which makes it unique among major social welfare legislation in this country, and perhaps all major legislation. In the end it passed only through the operations of rules mechanics, when the election of Scott Brown restored the filibuster to the Republicans. It’s being used as the basis for an HHS regulation that is blatantly unconstitutionalunder the First Amendment and RFRA, and it will redistribute health care in this country to a uniformly low level. It’s a tragedy that the final chapter to this lamentable path to passage would consist of such bad legal reasoning. Upholding it on Commerce Clause grounds would have been more constitutionally damaging, but more coherent. And, given Obama’s blatant refusal to order the enforcement of federal laws he doesn’t like, such as DOMA and immigrant deportation laws, Democrats will have no room for objection when a Republican President simply refuses to enforce Obamacare.


Monday, June 4, 2012

The Battle of Midway: 70 Years Ago Today

 Today is the 70th anniversary of the Battle of Midway and Admiral (then Rear Admiral) Raymond A. Spruance's celebrated victory and finest hour. Relatively junior and untested in carrier warfare, he went up against the Japanese varsity, in the persons of Admiral Isoroku Yamamoto and Vice Admiral ChÅ«ichi Nagumo, and (figuratively) handed them their heads. One of the most important moments in American military and naval history.  I personally rank it as one of the five most important battles in American history (the others being Saratoga, New Orleans, Vicksburg, and Gettysburg).  Let's remember Spruance, a largely unsung hero, along with all those who fought and died at Midway, especially the brave pilots of VT-6 and VT-8.